I’m off to a Reason-organized talk by David Stockman
shortly. It’s interesting how much his
stock has risen, perhaps especially among conservatives, as he continues the
economic-doom talk that got him denounced in the Reagan years for failure to be
a team player. (Perhaps one day it will
also be more acceptable among conservatives to favor increased immigration, and
Reason has something to say about that, too, or at least Shikha
Sood Dalmia draws some lessons from Canada.)
Charles Johnson (who might disagree with me, Dalmia, and for
that matter Reagan on immigration) thinks Calvin Coolidge is due for a favorable
reevaluation, too (he’s already my favorite president, not that I’m saying
there should be a government at all).
When not researching nefarious living
politicians, Johnson (a young Publius Fellow and one of my fellow Novak
Fellows) found time to write Why
Coolidge Matters: Leadership Lessons from America’s Most Underrated President,
and he makes a great case that both Coolidge’s many detractors and his
libertarian defenders tend to mistake his very active – but laissez-faire –
leadership for a sleepy, do-nothing style.
Coolidge here comes off as a tough decision-maker, albeit
one whose tendency to pick non-regulatory and non-tax solutions looked like
neglect to many intellectuals of his day and, soon, to the Progressive
historians who have since shaped how we see Coolidge.
To many, he is mainly remembered as the president before
Hoover and thus, presumably, one more person to blame for the subsequent
Depression – but whereas the Depression may have been slightly exacerbated by
Hoover and greatly exacerbated by FDR (conventional wisdom notwithstanding),
it’s worth noting that the 1920s prosperity Coolidge oversaw increased American
living standards by about half, with a substantial portion of those gains
withstanding even the subsequent Crash.
Coolidge as seen here should be of interest not only to
libertarians but to fusionist conservatives, since Coolidge blends even more
seamlessly than Reagan (who was influenced by Coolidge) a belief in
laissez-faire and a humbly-religious belief that America owed its prosperity
and success to a traditional moral foundation.
Progressives (if they’re open-minded!) might be intrigued by
the fact that Coolidge, as a Vermonter and then governor of Massachusetts,
before becoming vice president and president, was very much a Progressive in
the early-twentieth-century mold – but one who quickly became disillusioned
with the gap between legislative intentions and real-world outcomes. He often complained that America had begun
legislating faster than it could manage, predict, or understand the fallout of
law-making.
I can only imagine Coolidge would be as
chronically-horrified as Ron Paul if he saw Congress in action today with its
massive, unread bills (including, admittedly, immigration reform).
Here are ten bits from Why
Coolidge Matters that particularly caught my eye:
•Coolidge saw Bolshevism as a threat to civilization itself,
never recognized the USSR during his time in government, disagreed with
Progressive Woodrow Wilson about whether socialism was a menace, and (rightly)
saw the Industrial Workers of the World (the IWW or Wobblies) as the closest
thing in the U.S. to a rising threat of communist revolution.
•Coolidge not only preferred sticking to the principles of
the Founders – and evolution rather than revolution in American institutions –
he recognized that Progressives were continually (and dangerously) reinventing
the wheel and declaring it a novelty: “forever proposing something which is
old, and, because it has recently come to their attention, supposing it to be
new.”
De facto communism as cure-all was pushed by Plato long
before it was pushed by Progressives – or Occupy. None showed much real
understanding of economics.
•Coolidge understood that sustainable laws have to jibe with
people’s psychological inclinations (a point usually lost on technocrats, and
rationalists generally). Writes Johnson:
“[His] early education in the centrality of character to America’s founding
institutions helps to explain why Coolidge took such pains to restore America’s
heritage of freedom while in Washington.”
•Coolidge frequently praised the Declaration of
Independence, not just the Constitution, and to the extent he (like Johnson)
was more sympathetic than most modern libertarians to military intervention, it
was because, writes Johnson, America’s “truths could not be limited to her
shores.” Liberty for all, since all are
human.
•Coolidge was admirably consistent about letting government
investigations of internal wrongdoing run their course without interference and
without face-saving voluntary resignations, at one point saying of
investigations of the Secretary of the Navy and Attorney General, “I do not
propose to sacrifice any innocent man for my own welfare, nor do I propose to
retain in office any unfit man for my own welfare.”
•Even at a time when the Ku Klux Klan was immensely popular
– and disturbingly influential in both major parties – Coolidge denounced
eugenics as antithetical to American individualism, arguing for “a brotherhood
of Americans in a citizenship that rested on ideals, not race” – in an era when
Progressives like Wilson were enamored of eugenics and had been increasing segregation in the federal
government.
Nonetheless, historians have tried to lay the blame for the
attitudes of the era at Coolidge’s feet.
•Coolidge threatened martial law in states where the
apparatus of government had been overtaken by Klan mobs, including Oklahoma,
despite a majority of the legislators in the lower house of the state
reportedly being Klansmen.
•Coolidge tried but failed to prevent anti-Japanese clauses
from being included in immigration legislation, objecting to the idea that there
was a science of ethnology that differentiated between the rights of different
groups.
•Coolidge contended in his day, as we do now, with the
misleading argument that there is a clash between the rights of people and the
rights “of property,” saying in his 1925 Inaugural Address, “I favor the policy
of economy, not because I wish to save money, but because I wish to save
people.”
•After he left office, he soon chastised Hoover and other
politicians who deviated from Coolidge’s laissez-faire, writing in his popular
newspaper column in terms that would warm the heart of an Austrian economist,
“Almost all these [post-Crash regulatory] suggestions are for artificial rules
of conduct to save a situation from the inevitable consequences of the force of
natural laws...Neither the state nor the Federal government can supply the
information and wisdom necessary to direct the business activity of the
nation.”
Mister, we could use a man like Calvin Coolidge again.
5 comments:
He promptly criticised Hoover and other politicians who departed from Coolidge's laissez-faire in his well-read newspaper column after leaving office, using language that would make an Austrian economist smile.
Coolidge as seen here should be of interest not only to libertarians, but also to fusionist conservatives, because Coolidge blends laissez-faire and a humbly-religious belief best book writing services USA that America owed its prosperity and success to a traditional moral foundation even more seamlessly than Reagan (who was influenced by Coolidge).
He explores Coolidge's commitment to free-market economics, his advocacy for small government, and his steadfast belief in the importance of individual rights and limited intervention.
In his thought-provoking book, "Why Coolidge Matters," Charles Johnson delves into the life and legacy of President Calvin Coolidge, shedding light on why this often-overlooked leader remains relevant today.
He delves into Coolidge's dedication to free-market economics, his support for small government, and his unwavering belief in the significance of individual rights and minimal intervention.
Post a Comment